18
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
THE POST-NEOLIBERAL SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT
EL DESARROLLO POST-NEOLIBERAL DE AMÉRICA DEL SUR
ABSTRACT
RESUMEN
This study addressed the triangular relations between Latin America, Beijing and Washington
in the last 15 years using a process tracing technique on the economic and political models of
the region. It specically focused on the South American development during the post-Washin-
gton Consensus era, as well as the expanding inuence of China over this region. The aim of
this paper was to transmit the idea that the failure of neoliberalism in the 90s together with the
expansionism of China have shaped the contemporary political and economic arena among the
countries of South America. This work could help to understand the historical process of the
construction of develop paradigms on the region and its impact on the society.
Keywords: China, Development, Hegemonic Powers, Latin-America, United States.
Este estudio analizó las relaciones triangulares entre América Latina, Pekín y Washington en
los últimos 15 años por medio de un rastreo del proceso político y económico de los estados
de la región. Se centró especícamente en el desarrollo de América del Sur durante la era
post-neoliberal, y la creciente inuencia de China sobre esta región. El objetivo de este trabajo
fue promulgar la idea de que los medios por los cuales se ha formado la arena política y eco-
nómica contemporánea de los países latinoamericanos han sido, el fracaso de las doctrinas del
Consenso de Washington en los años noventa en conjunto el expansionismo chino. El aporte
del presente trabajo va dirigido a la comprensión del proceso histórico de la construcción de
paradigmas de desarrollo en la región y su impacto en la sociedad.
Palabras Clave: China, Desarrollo, Poderes Hegemónicos, América Latina, Estados Unidos.
Santiago Carranco Paredes
scarrancoparedes@gmail.com
Universidad Internacional del Ecuador
Flacso, Ecuador
Fecha recepción: 20/02/2018
Fecha aceptación: 30/03/2018
19
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
INTRODUCTION
The new millennium embodied a breakpoint
in Latin American politics. After 20 years of
adjustment, which was the subtle term used
for referring to the neoliberal guidelines
imposed by international nancial institu-
tions (Williamson 1990:7), a wave of leftist
leaders that promoted anti-neoliberal ideo-
logies gained popularity among the public.
The socialist trend started in 1998 with the
triumph of Hugo Chavez in Venezuela, fo-
llowed by the victory of the Workers Party in
Brazil led by Ignacio Lula da Silva in 2002.
Then, a series of populist left-wing leaders
gained power as in the case of Rafael Correa
in Ecuador in 2007, Evo Morales in Bolivia
in 2006 and the former guerrilla man Jose
Mújica in Uruguay in 2010.
Some of this left-winged leader have alig-
ned with the ideas of the ‘21st Century So-
cialism’, promulgated by Heinz Dieterich in
1996 and then restructured at the Sao Paulo
forum by the socialist South American lea-
ders. Rafael Correa (2014) set that it is not
considered a model, but a series of princi-
ples that allows sovereign governments to
generate economic and political models that
are suitable for their own domestic reality.
The four main principles of this doctrine are:
Prevalence of human capital over nan-
cial capital
• Major use of direct democracy
• Special protection for minority groups
Self-determination and nationalization
(Dieterich 2003:121-129)
Such series of principles have shaped the
economic and political models in some sta-
tes, for instance El Buen Vivir in Ecuador,
a model that provides constitutional rights
to the Earth and the environment, as well as
the Bolivariano model of Venezuela shaped
by Hugo Chavez, and the Sumac Kumaña in
Bolivia. Such models were aimed to convert
Latin America into a region integrated under
socialist patterns.
In general terms, during the rst decade
of this millennium, those projects have de-
monstrated a positive progress in economic
terms. The GDP of the region has grown
around 4.5% each year and the unemploy-
ment rates have fallen from 11.2% in 2002 to
6.4% in 2011. Furthermore, Latin America
has lifted more than 64 million people from
poverty and 60 million from the absolute po-
verty line; and, except for Venezuela, the re-
gion has maintained constantly low ination
levels (Cepal 2015). Some authors such as
Do Alto (2008), Svampa (2008) and Paniz-
za (2009) have suggested that the autonomy
in the Post-Washington Consensus policies
have been the key factor that led to South
American states to achieve such political and
economic stability. However, there are fur-
ther aspects such as Chinese expansionism
that has evidently inuenced the progress of
the region during the last 15 years.
The South American governments have en-
joyed an economic bonanza in the last deca-
de, primarily produced by two factors. First,
a boom of the commodities market cau-
sed by Chinese demand for raw materials;
and second, the increment of capital ows
towards the region, from countries like Sou-
th Korea, Canada, Australia, and expressly
from China. Therefore, it is conceivable that
the stability of the mentioned leftist gover-
nments along with the success of their po-
licies may perhaps be associated in a direct
way with the expanding inuence from the
Asian power over the region. Authors as
Manriquez & Alvarez (2014), Wu & De Wei
(2014) and Philips (2011), have paid special
attention to the increasing expansion of Chi-
nese inuence over South America.
Nowadays, China is the leading world expor-
ter and the 2nd major economy in the world
(Francoise 2013:25-26). In terms of bilateral
trading with Latin America, the commerce
gures climbed sharply during the rst deca-
de of the millennium; the Sino–Latin Ame-
rican trade skyrocketed from US$10 billion
in 2000 to a pre-crisis peak of over US$143
billion in 2008. China became either the rst
or second largest trading partner for most
Latin American countries. Meanwhile, La-
tin America has become China’s fth-largest
20
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
METHODOLOGY
This scientic paper is the result of a research
that aimed to investigate the connexion that
exist between the failures of the Neoliberal
guidelines in the South American countries
during the 90s and the Chinese expansio-
nism over the world. The connexion will be
reected on the change of the development
paradigms that has shaped the contemporary
political-economy arena of the region. At
the end of this work paper, the reader will
acquire an understanding about the way in
which the upsurge of the Chinese power has
inuenced the policy-making of the South
American states over the last 15 years. The
argument will be developed over 3 parts.
The rst one will be dedicated to discus-
sing about the on-going power shifts in the
international-political arena. This part will
include a narrative about the failure of the
Washington Consensus guidelines, as well
as a clarication about the details of the
contemporary power struggle between the
main contemporary hegemonic powers, in
order to recuperate this data, the study used
a documentation of primary and secondary
sources. The aim of this section is to set the
actual scenery of the interrelations between
Beijing, Washington and South America.
The second part aims to dene the connec-
tion between the Chinese expansion and the
rise of leftist governments in South Ameri-
ca. This section will include a study about
the uprising of the left over the region, par-
ticularly after the failure of the Washington
Consensus. It also will include an illustra-
tion of the macroeconomic indicators of the
performance of the region over the last 15
years, with the intention of evaluating whe-
ther the domestic policies created in some
countries of South America after the Was-
hington Consensus have created real deve-
lopment in the region or if it was merely a
ctitious growth.
trading partner (León-Manriquez & Hearn
2011:11-12).
As well, for some South American adminis-
trations, including the ones in Ecuador, Ve-
nezuela and the Argentinean before Macri,
the Chinese government has turned into the
new alternative for nancial assistance, in
some way setting aside the inuence of the
traditional international nancial institutions
as the International Monetary Found (IMF).
Agreeing to Chinese borrowing terms do not
include any type of policy reforms or scal
adjustment.
Instead, the Asian state mostly requires the
recognition of the One-China policy and the
signing of long-term commercial contracts,
headed to supply China a daily xed quan-
tity of commodities; in most of the cases,
oil, minerals and natural gas (Wu & De Wei
2014:790). In this way, China does not only
ensure a long-term supply of commodities,
but also gains recognition of its national line
of thought. In the same manner, South Ame-
rican governments, benet from market di-
versication, as well as nancial assistance
without any requirements of policy adjust-
ment.
The expanding inuence of China over de-
veloping regions has brought debates about
the geopolitical implications of China’s rise.
One standpoint perceives China as a threat
to the United States’ position as the sole su-
perpower. This challenge to US hegemony
could be a cause of instability and poten-
tial conict in the future. However, further
views have emphasised the peaceful rise of
China, and the benets of its expansionism.
One example of it was mentioned before: It
is how the commodity boom over the last 15
years, along with the nancial aid and spe-
cialised investment made by China has brou-
ght an economic expansion for developing
economies, particularly to South America.
In this way, the Chinese economy could be
complementary to those of other developing
countries that stand to gain from China’s
growth (Rhys 2010:810-812).
21
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION:
The Decalogue for Development
Finally, the third section will provide 3 par-
ticular case study using a process tracing
technique, in which by analysing the neoli-
beral guidelines that led Argentina, Bolivia
and Ecuador to a nancial or an economic
crisis, along with a study about expansion in
economic and diplomatic bilateral relations
with China, I aim to oer a narrowed and ac-
curate perspective of the way in which these
factors have been an essential foundation for
the construction of the current economic and
public policies of those countries, as well as
the real impacts these policies have had du-
ring this period of time.
During the 60s and the 70s, Latin American
states acquired substantial sums of foreign
debt, particularly with the IMF for adjusting
the disproportion on its balance of payments.
Such imbalances were mainly caused by the
ineciency of import substitution policies
that those states maintained after World War
II.
An example of such practices was using fo-
reign loans to protect the state enterprises,
compensating its inecacy and making them
able to compete at domestic level. In this
way, the South American states were using
the nancial loans provided by the IMF not
only to correct macroeconomic imbalances,
but also to nance the public industry de-
cit. By 1980, most Latin America economies
became immersed in economic stagation,
mainly triggered by the collapse of the raw
materials markets and the US Dollar appre-
ciation (Rangel & Soto Reyes 2012:42).
In 1982 the Mexican state, which was unable
to borrow, ran out of nancial reserves and
this situation ultimately led to default on its
foreign debt. The Mexican default triggered
a series of complications for all Latin Ameri-
can states. The US authorities alleged that to
avoid a contagious ination, it was necessary
to restrict the quantity of money circulating
in the economy. Thus, the North-American
state increased their interest rates producing
a rise in the price of their currency. The La-
tin American states, which were indebted in
US Dollars, attained a foreign debt capable
to reach record levels. Consequently, much
of states in the region fell into a situation that
made them unable repay their foreign debt.
To avoid a massive default, the internatio-
nal institutional creditors came into the res-
cue. However, they also viewed a perfect
opportunity to extend the neoliberal system
to South America (Rangel & Soto Reyes
2012:40-45). After the failure of the Cepa-
list model of import substitution, the Latin
22
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
American states were required an open, sta-
ble and liberalized economic model.
At least this was the prescription that neo-
liberal economists of the time suggested,
including Williamson (1990) and Richard
(1990). This is how the neoliberal guidelines
were crystallized with the formulation of the
Washington Consensus. A Decalogue of po-
licy reforms which fundamentally proposed
that economic reforms should be based on
the logic of the markets, besides from being
characterized by openness and macroecono-
mic principles. The Washington Consensus
could, therefore, be summarized by ten main
guidelines:
• Fiscal Discipline
Redirection of public expenditure towards
education, healthcare and infrastructure
• Tax reforms to extend the tax base
• Interest rate liberalization
A competitive exchange rates
• Trade liberalization
• Liberalization of foreign investment in-
ows
• Privatization
• Deregulation to commerce
• Property Rights (Williamson 1990)
The eects of the Washington Consensus
over Latin America raised, and still raises,
several arguments concerned with debates
about the triumph or failure of liberalism
and the way in which globalization is percei-
ved. However, it is undeniable that the libe-
ral guidelines were unsatisfactory for Latin
America since they did not accomplish their
main objective.
As a matter of fact, after a decade of its im-
plementation, states such as Argentina, Bo-
livia, Brazil, Ecuador, Paraguay, Venezuela
and Uruguay were hit by a series of econo-
mic, nancial and political issues that could
most certainly be linked to the unsatisfactory
reaction of the public towards the neolibe-
ral policies implemented during the 90s. In
addition, the implementation and the main-
tenance of the neoliberal policies caused the
South American countries to acquire an even
larger amount of foreign debt.
Such a situation produced a vicious cycle, in
which the states needed money to maintain
the neoliberal policies, but then again, the
International Financial Institutions only pro-
vided them conditionally loans, upon the im-
plementation of further neoliberal policies.
Such a situation made it impossible for the
South American states to redirect the money
of their loans to matters that would enhance
their development like education, infrastruc-
ture and technology. Instead it was used to
pay the cost of policy implementations, and
23
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
the repayment of their debts with higher in-
terest rates. Consequently, these states were
not able to industrialize their production and
were condemned to be indebted raw material
exporters (Rangel & Soto Reyes 2012:46-
57).
The Chinese expansion and the US hege-
monic decline
While Latin America entered a decade of
economic stagnation in the 80s, China on
the other hand was starting a period of rapid
economic growth. Since the 80s, the Chine-
se economy not only has grown at almost
10 per cent per annum, which resulted in a
sevenfold increase in the income per capi-
ta. But it has also become the second-largest
economy in the world. Furthermore, its suc-
cessful reintegration to the global economy
had situated the Asian power as the world’s
largest exporter ahead of Germany and Ja-
pan. In addition, Chinese companies such as
Sinopec and China National Petroleum have
become key players in the commodities mar-
ket, particularly in the extraction and energy
industries. Since 2000, the Asian power has
been expanding its inuence in the world
beyond commerce. China started having a
major impact on the political, nancial and
diplomatic aairs.
Manriquez & Alvarez (2014), demostrated
how Latin America is still a highly econo-
mic-dependent region, and also they out-
lined the ideological, political and mostly
economic ssures of the relations between
United States and Latin America. They went
on to explain how China is taking advan-
tage of this situation in order to gain more
inuence over the Latin Amercian region.
Even though the general perspective of the
US-Latin American relations shows a solid
compromise, the reality is revealed when the
studies are geographically separated. As it
could be seen in table 2, the total trade be-
tween the two parties rose from US$ 339
billion in 2000, to US$ 586 billion in 2012.
In addition, Latin America has gained rele-
vance in US foreign trade gures. In 1990,
the region accounted for 13.3% of US ex-
ports and 12.9% of US imports. By 2009,
the respective shares increased to 22.1% and
18.1% respectively (Cepal 2015). However,
58% of US trade with Latin America took
place with Mexico, and the commercial ow
of the nineteen other states accounted for
just US$ 340 billion. Furthermore, while the
United States is still the major commercial
partner of almost all the countries in Cen-
tral America and in the Caribbean, China
has displaced the United States as the major
commercial partner in many South American
states (Manriquez & Alvarez 2014:8-14).
There are several factors that are contribu-
ting to the capacity of China to overstep the
United States’ economic and political in-
uence in the region. For Manriquez & Al-
varez (2014:11-12) the list includes rst, the
geographical conditions, in which the Uni-
ted States is still able to inuence states with
geographical contiguity, but is inecient
to maintain its control over all the states in
the region. Second, the US neglect for Latin
America due to its focus on the Middle East.
And third, a lack of trust in the orthodox
neoliberal guidelines.
On the other hand, China has emerged in La-
tin America as the new nancial alternative.
China has disbursed since 2010, more than
US$110 billion in high-level investment to
Latin America and nowadays has become
the 3rd highest investor in this region. Fur-
thermore, China has become a donor-mem-
ber for the Inter-American Development
Bank (IDB), providing China a seat on the
Board of Governors, allowing China the ca-
pacity to inuence decision-making in terms
of nancial policies and investment of the
26 Latin American countries part of the IDB
(Wu & De Wei 2014).
The nancial power of China is becoming
its most ecient weapon to expand its in-
uence. Nowadays, China has accumulated
US$3.4 trillion of ocial foreign exchan-
ge reserves. Furthermore, it is the second
biggest creditor of the US foreign debt
(US$1164 billons [7.5% of the total United
States foreign debt]). Although the United
States still maintains privileges due the po-
sition of the US dollar as the key currency of
24
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
the world, the massive accumulation of Chi-
nese nancial assets has situated the United
States in a very sensitive position, as the Chi-
nese expansion of nancial inuence over
the United States is aecting its hegemonic
political capabilities. Thus, the United States
is watching carefully how China continues
to expand its inuence over the South Ame-
rican region, and considering how best to act
to not aect its own nancial stability.
The former Australian Prime Minister, Ke-
vin Rudd (2015), now president of the Asia
Society Policy Institute, declared that:
If China does become the world’s
largest economy, it will be the
rst time in 200 years that in the
world we will have as the largest
economy a non-English speaking
country, a non-Western country,
and a non-liberal democratic coun-
try…It will aect so many things
at so many levels. It will go to
the absolute core. It’s happening
quietly. It is happening persistent-
ly. It is happening in some senses
under the radar’. (Rudd 2015:1)
Such description perfectly captures how
China has expanded its inuence over de-
veloping regions, particularly in North Afri-
ca and Latin America. Being a great power
has never been solely about the possession
of large amounts of crude material power. It
has been closely related to notions of legiti-
macy and authority, in this way, the Chinese
power has been combined with a long-term
sense of where it would like to be and that, as
a state, it must date maintained a signicant
degree of strength and coherence (Hurrell
2006). Since 2001, the presence of China in
South America has intensied, and this it is
not a coincidence.
The aliation of China to the World Trade
Organization (WTO) changed commercial
rules all over the globe. The leftist gover-
nments saw an opportunity to expand their
markets to Southeast Asian states and parti-
cularly to China, which had already started
to increase its commerce over the region du-
ring the late 90s. The commercial guidelines
of all the South American states have started
to include openness to Chinese markets as
key goals in their foreign and commercial
policies (Oliva 2010:113).
Attempting to generate a dierent scheme
of cooperation comprising the non-Western
Southern regions of the globe, China has
chosen a softer pattern of inuence, which
has given the impression to be solely concer-
ned with commercial matters at rst glance,
but later pursuing political and diplomatic
acknowledgment. For instance, China has
changed its policy and now can expand its
commercial ow and direct its investment
towards developing countries that still main-
tains good relations with Taiwan, such as
Honduras, Guatemala and Paraguay. This
has been done deliberately with the aim of
opening further diplomatic channels later
down the line, such as happened in 2004
and 2007, with the Dominican Republic and
Costa Rica respectively, both Caribbean sta-
tes which have maintained a historical sche-
me of cooperation with Taiwan but switched
rapidly their diplomatic recognition of the
People’s Republic of China when they per-
ceived that doing so would be benecial
(Manriquez & Álvarez 2014:22) (Wu & De
Wei 2014:795-797).
China is also pursuing a recognition as a
market economy state, regardless of its mer-
cantilist practices, which include an articial
depreciated currency exchange rate, dum-
ping, copyright infringements, various cases
of child labour and extreme working condi-
tions. In South America, states as Argentina,
Peru, Venezuela Brazil and Chile, without
regard of the counter eects that such condi-
tions have on their own commercial sectors,
have granted China the condition of a market
economy state, since Chinese ocials have
imposed this condition to continue a com-
mercial and nancial scheme of cooperation
(Urdinez 2014).
The Sino diplomacy and its inuence for
the upsurge of the leftist policies in the
South
Wu & De Wei (2014:789-799), have recog-
nized two main areas of Chinese foreign po-
licy inuence over Latin American states.
25
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
The rst is concerned with nances and the
economy. It includes oil negotiations, com-
mercial reliance, borrowing and investment.
The second area is about diplomatic recog-
nition and political expansionism, including
the global recognition of the ‘One China’
Policy.
One of the bases of the success of the Chine-
se expansion in South America had been re-
lated to the platforms that China used since
2000 for engaging with these nations in eco-
nomic aairs, leaving the pursuit of diplo-
matic recognition as a secondary priority. By
doing so, China has been welcomed by the
South American states as an option to diver-
sify its markets and for obtaining nancial
aid and investments. China has focused on
creating solid relations based on economic
and nancial matters rst and, after securing
these, branching out into the diplomatic and
ideological arena. It is evident that China has
learned the lesson of the failure of the neo-
liberal scheme managed during the 80s and
the 90s. (Wu & De Wei 2014:800)
The leftist projects in Latin America de-
monstrated decent outcomes, which could
be validated by both the popular acceptan-
ce of the leftist leaders during their admi-
nistrations as well as the good results given
by macroeconomic indicators, which shown
a consistent expansion on the GDP growth
rates per year and a decrease in ination and
unemployment rates; in comparison to the
numbers during the Washington Consensus
reforms in the 90s. However, since 2014, the
popularity of the leaders has started to decli-
ne, because of two important factors. First,
criticism about the increasing levels of ac-
cumulation in both public and foreign debt,
particularly with China. And second, the rec-
kless allocation of public funds, especially
in the Andean region administrations, inclu-
ding Bolivia, Ecuador, Argentina but, most
expressly, Venezuela.
Saul Quincy (2011) determined that these
are common problems with socialist models,
which denote the unsustainability of such
projects for two reasons. Firstly, because
leftist leaders have only focused on winning
socialist goals, preventing any alternative
for the model that they have proposed and
therefore showing the populist and self-in-
terested characteristics of such models. And
secondly, due to the lack of empathy of the
professionals and middle classes towards the
social policies, probably because they have
been educated under neoliberal bases. In Ve-
nezuela for instance, the professional class is
so ideologically capitalist that even doctors
must be imported from Cuba to work in the
public sector as, so few Venezuelan doctors
are willing to treat the poor if their personal
income is aected. (Quincy 2011)
The Argentinean Case
In Argentina, six of the ten neoliberal poli-
cies were applied for the economic restruc-
turing of the state including a xed nominal
exchange rate, trade liberalization, an inten-
sive privatization scheme, and deregulation
of the labour conditions, allowing outsour-
cing and non-contractual ways of employ-
ment. Silva (2015), studied the reformation
into two sub-periods.
The rst period of boom, started in 1991 and
extended up until the third quarter of 1998
and the second one of crisis, which begins
in the fourth quarter of 1998 and lasts up to
the end of 2001. It is true that during the rst
period the neoliberal policies had an accep-
table performance, not only by facilitating
the expansion of the Argentinean markets,
but also by pressuring companies to become
more productive.
However, the ipside of this process was the
accumulation of nancial and scal imba-
lances caused by the cost of implementing
and maintaining these neoliberal policies,
especially the cost of maintaining the pari-
ty of the Argentina Peso to the US Dollar.
In addition, there was a deterioration in sta-
te power due to the austerity measures im-
posed, which was clearly expressed in the
breakup of the alliances in parliament, and a
general loss of legitimacy among their elec-
toral base, producing apart from the econo-
mic unproductivity, a profound political ins-
tability.
The Argentinean crisis best known as the Co-
rralito was triggered in 2001 when the IMF
26
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
refused to release US$1.3 billion, alleging
the failure of the Argentinean government to
reach a previously agreed-upon budget de-
cit target, while it also demanded further
budget cuts. This episode not only caused a
national demonization of the neoliberal ins-
titutions but also the spreading of a sense of
discomfort to the whole population, espe-
cially to the most aected working classes.
The situation led to a prolonged crisis, which
ended in nancial bankruptcy and a severe
decline on real economy. Argentina ended in
a situation where the bank accounts of the
people were frozen for weeks, and 50% of
the population ocially became poor while
another 25% was below the absolute line of
poverty (Silva 2015).
The Argentinian nancial is one example
of a vast range of events that demonstrated
not only the unpopularity of the neoliberal
policy among Latin Americans, but also the
means in which the reckless implementation
of these policies was never able to adjust to
the South American reality, resulting in a
asco that cost all the countries of the region
various decades of unproductivity and large
sums of nancial obligations.
Although there is still a divergence of opi-
nions about the outcomes of the Washing-
ton Consensus in South America, a general
perception among the authors, regardless of
whether they are supporters or opponents of
neoliberal dogmas and including the pers-
pectives of Cavallo (2004), Silva (2015)
and Rangel & Soto Reyes (2012), is that
the Washington Consensus left a sense of
economic openness in Latin America and
helped to rationalize the concept of globali-
zation for Latin Americans. Nevertheless, it
also left an unpopular notion about neolibe-
ral institutions and the scheme in which they
were regulated.
The new-born Sino-Argentinean relations
during the Kirchner administration were a
good example to demonstrate the inuence
that Chinese diplomacy has over the econo-
mic and political decisions taken during this
period. In 2003, after several interim presi-
dents, the left-wing leader, Nestor Kirchner
became Argentinean president. The Kirch-
ner administration pursued an autonomous
economic policy that was contrary to the
guidelines imposed by the IMF in the 90s.
The main objective of the Argentinean go-
vernment became the repayment of the debt,
with the intention to disassociate the country
from neoliberal prescriptions imposed by the
multilaterals. Since its rst day in the admi-
nistration, Kirchner implemented a series of
social programs to reconsolidate the Argen-
tinean people’s trust in the government and
such measures boosted his popularity among
the public and provided political stability to
Argentina (Panizza 2009:245). In 2006, Ar-
gentina achieved its national goal by paying
its debt with a single payment of US$ 9.2
billion (Navarro 2015). It could be said that
somehow, the autonomous policies reco-
vered the Argentinean economy and made
the state able to repay its debt obligations.
However, there is an essential factor which
facilitated the Argentinean recovery, and
such factor indeed is China.
Since 2003 the strategic foreign policy goals
of Argentina started to include guidelines
which encouraged openness and enhance-
ment of diplomatic and commercial relations
towards the Asiatic power. In fact, China
was considered one of the seven great pivo-
tal points of Argentinean commercial policy
which aimed to create permanent, balanced
and mutual bilateral ties. In 2004, Kirchner
visited Beijing and Shanghai accompanied
by his ministers and his wife, Cristina Fer-
nandez, who in 2007 would be elected as
President of Argentina. This was the rst of
many future encounters between Argenti-
nean and Chinese leaders. Because of such
visits, a series of bilateral agreements were
signed, mostly to promote mutual invest-
ment and to encourage the creation of Si-
no-Argentine companies.
For China, the recognition as a market eco-
nomy by the government of Argentina was
a key issue. However, the Argentinean sta-
te was applying 79 anti-dumping measures
per year to Chinese products to protect its
industry and workers. Nonetheless, China
was oering a considerable increase in in-
vestment towards Argentina’s productive
27
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
sectors and infrastructure, besides it provi-
ded Argentina the status of tourist destina-
tion and, most important, accepted to provi-
de the nancial aid that Argentina needed to
full its national prime objective, which was
to pay back the debt. What’s more, Hu Jin-
tao had already gained the recognition from
Brazilian’s president, Luiz Ignacio Lula da
Silva, which would have conditioned the
bargaining power of Argentinean ocials
who knew that granting China the condition
of ‘market economy’ could produce dange-
rous eects on their national industry. Yet,
before Jintao left South America, the nego-
tiations concluded with the signing of a ‘me-
morandum of mutual understanding’ which
recognized China as a market economy state
(Urdinez 2014:70-73). This exposed the vul-
nerable sectors of the Argentinean economy
and demonstrated the capabilities of the Chi-
nese ocials who, by including nancial
and commercial matters into the bargain, can
inuence a country’s diplomacy and ideolo-
gy.
In addition, since 2005, Chinese injections of
capital started to be introduced into Argenti-
na’s economy through direct investment and
lending. The same year, China purchased
Argentinean debt bonds, which were mainly
issued with the purpose of meeting its nan-
cial obligations with the IMF. So, because
of this, further Chinese investment was used
for improving the public infrastructure such
as highways and railways. In return, Argen-
tina agreed to take a common stance against
US and European agriculture subsidies in
the WTO (Urdinez 2014).
Since 2006, there has been a series of bila-
teral agreements signed by both parties with
the aim of boosting cooperation in areas that
include natural gas, tobacco and pharmaceu-
tical commercialization, as well as tourism,
educational services, and biotechnology
transfers, and the consolidation of the Chi-
na-MERCOSUR agreement. Furthermore,
in 2009, a fund of US$ 11 billion in Pesos and
Renminbi was created between the Argenti-
nean Central Bank and the People’s Bank of
China to set commercial transactions in both
national currencies. Hence, both countries
have cooperated in taking small steps to set
aside dependency on the US dollar for inter-
national transactions (Oliva 2010:104-105).
By the analyses of the present Sino-Argenti-
nean relations, it is possible to observe that
the interrelations of both countries go be-
yond the economic and commercial matters.
Nowadays, it is clear to observe a demar-
cated scheme of cooperation between these
nations that include diplomatic, political and
ideological bonds. China was a crucial pla-
yer in the Argentinean recovery and nowa-
days plays a fundamental role as commercial
partner and investor for the maintenance of
its policies. On the other hand, Argentina has
become largely dependent on China, which
has demonstrated the power to inuence Ar-
gentinean executive decisions.
Bolivia, Morales and China
After 20 years of neoliberal guidelines, the
Bolivian state was immersed into a profound
economic and social crisis. The Washington
Consensus policies brought to this country,
an increment in poverty rates while wealth
was accumulated by a few sectors and taken
outside the country. Furthermore, the gap
between rich and poor widened, the infor-
mal economy numbers skyrocketed, and the
high levels of unemployment caused people
to work for less than US $ 1 per day (Rowan
2003:2-3).
Such precarious conditions resulted into a
natural response in which Bolivian taxpa-
yers redirected their frustration to oppose
any neoliberal policy. For Do Alto (2008)
and Panizza (2009), the failure of the Was-
hington Consensus guidelines triggered the
popularity of the left anti-elitist leader, Evo
Morales, which appeared with a demagogi-
cally-social discourse that not only attacked
aggressively the neoliberalist line of thou-
ght, but also induced a feeling of nationalism
within the Bolivian collective mind. Since
Bolivian policies took a shift against neoli-
beralism (Rowan 2003:2).
A brief valuation of social and economic in-
dicators of Morales` administration shown
that the GDP has been constantly growing
around 4.1% and 6.1% each year. In addi-
28
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
tion, the minimum wage escalated from US$
57 in 2003 to US$ 238 in 2015, furthermore,
the infant mortality rate was reduced by 60%
and most importantly, 3 million people have
been lifted out of poverty and 1.7 million
from extreme poverty (Cepal 2015). Al-
though the Bolivian economy is still fragile
and dependant, the left policies of the multi-
cultural state have demonstrated remarkably
better outcomes than the results produced
by the policies applied during the neoliberal
period; however, again China, was an impor-
tant player that aimed for such development.
There are two important factors in the
Evo-Bolivian model. The rst one stands for
the nationalisation of public goods, such as
water and electricity, as well as the ones con-
cerned with extraction of hydrocarbons and
mining, which are constitutional recognized
as strategic resources. Do Alto (2008:177-
183) studied the eects of the nationaliza-
tion of companies in Bolivia, so he remar-
ked that in addition to the new Constitution,
there are two key legal reforms that helped
the Bolivian government to succeed in the
nationalization process without using the -
gure of expropriation.
The rst was the supreme decree N. 29701
and the second the Hydrocarbons’ law. The
rst established that 82% of the prot of
big companies in the extractive industries
should go to the state and 50% of the prot
for the minor ones. The second one dictates
that all the hydrocarbon resources belong to
the state. As a result, the Bolivian govern-
ment has been able to benet directly from
the boom in the commodities market of the
last decades. The Bolivian government has
already gained control of 19% of the Boli-
vian GDP, and the national objectives expect
that they can get control of 30% of its GDP.
The second factor is related to an increase of
exports, mainly attributed to the diversica-
tion of its markets, predominantly towards
China.
In the last decades, the Chinese industrial
production has diversied from its tradi-
tional industries such as toys and textiles
production to further segments such as ma-
chinery and chemical production. The rapid
development of China’s productivity base
has increased its demand of raw materials.
Since 2001, China has become the greatest
importer of minerals and metallic commodi-
ties such as tin, zinc, steel, lead and copper.
Which produced that the global raw mate-
rial supply was insucient to go together
with the world’s growing demand for such
products. Consequently, the prices started to
rise rapidly and created a boom in the com-
modities market (Poveda 2010:153-154).
The boom in the new Sino industries caused
Bolivia to ourish during the last decades.
The Bolivian economy is limited to the su-
pply of natural resources, and as an exporter
of only a few commodities, it is highly sen-
sitive to any matters that occur in the glo-
bal markets. Consequently, the multicultural
state beneted greatly from the commodity
boom caused by the Chinese demand.
29
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
Compared to the 90s, in the XXI century,
Bolivian exports have increased from US$
1307 million in 1996, to US$ 4245 million
in 2006 (INE 2007). Such increment is the
result of a market diversication, as can be
seen in the Figure 3. Export growth to Asia
and China was especially remarkable with
an increase from 0.32% of Bolivian exports
share in 1996 to 9.87% in 2006. Thus, Asia
has become Bolivia’s second most impor-
tant trade partner in the region. On the other
hand, it is possible to observe that the trade
share of the US and the EU has plummeted.
This situation could be a result of Evo Mora-
les’s resolution to refuse to sign a free trade
agreement with the US as well as the natio-
nalization of European and North-American
companies.
Chinese investment has also played a key
role in Bolivian economic expansion. The-
re are two recent projects of cooperation
between China and Bolivia that prove this.
The rst is an agreement for a joint venture
between the Chinese company Shengli and
the Bolivian Ministry of Hydrocarbons, in
which Shengli will invest almost $2 billion
in the assessment, extraction and processing
of petroleum and natural gas in the north of
the La Paz region.
And the second is a cooperation project in
which both governments will invest in the
elaboration of a geological map of Bolivia.
For these projects China will invest $60 mi-
llion in the elaboration of 70% of Bolivia’s
geological map. Consequently, Bolivia will
be able to vastly improve their hydrocarbon
and mining industries, while China would
then have a preference in the extraction bu-
siness (Poveda 2010:160-165).
Populism in the bonanza
China played an important part in the main-
tenance of the populist practices of some ad-
ministrations. The direct investment, nan-
cial aid, and the increasing commercial ow
have brought extraordinary revenues for the
Latin American governments. Such incomes
have been redirected in some states to popu-
list practices to boost the popularity of the
leaders.
For example, in 2007, Costa Rica followed
the road of the Dominican Republic that in
2004 cut relations with Taiwan, due to an en-
couraging oer from The People’s Republic
of China that could boost their popularity
among the public. China oered that, in ex-
change of the recognition of the ‘One-China
policy’ Costa Rica and the Dominican Repu-
blic will receive US$ 100 million and US$
122 million respectively for the construction
of national stadiums. Both countries found
that this oer was more benecial than Tai-
wan’s oer, that included US$70 million in
aid for Costa Rica and 6.8 US$ million in
assistance for the Dominican Republic (Wu
& De Wei 2014:789).
30
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
A further case of social polices includes
countries as Ecuador, Bolivia and Venezuela
which have been able to expand the public
sector, and to reduce unemployment rates by
using Chinese foreign investment to create
unproductive public entities to provide jobs.
For example, when Hugo Chavez got elec-
ted, Venezuela had 16 ministries. By 2013,
the number of ministries doubled to 32 and
employed 19.6% of the Venezuelan labour
force; while in Colombia, which maintained
a pro-market system, there were 16 minis-
tries which employed 3.5% of the Colom-
bian labour force (Torres 2015).
Venezuela has received US$ 42.5 billion in
loans from the Chinese Development Bank
for improving public infrastructure. None-
theless, in lending terms, the infrastructure
includes the construction, renovation and
expansion of public buildings which were
used to house new public entities with the
aim of producing articial jobs (Wu & De
Wei 2014:92).
The expansion of the Venezuelan public sec-
tor which meant an extensive increase in the
public spending has only been possible as it
was nanced by the extraordinary revenues
that Venezuela has received during the last
decades as product of the high prices of oil
during this period. Venezuela’s oil revenues,
according to the Opec (2015), accounts for
about 95% of export earnings and the oil and
gas sector represents around 25 % of the Ve-
nezuelan GDP.
In 2014, when the commodity boom ended,
and the prices of fossil fuels dropped, Vene-
zuela’s president, Nicolas Maduro, imple-
mented an emergency readjustment program
to cut public spending, reducing its number
of ministries to 28. The Venezuelan oil barre-
ls went from a price of around US$ 100 per
barrel, to US$ 55 per barrel in 2015, causing
an economic recession and a decit in the
balance of payments and resulting in uncon-
trollable ination of 52.7%, and an expan-
sion in the numbers of Venezuelans who live
in poverty and extreme poverty conditions
(32.5% and 9.8% correspondingly). Conse-
quently, Nicolas Maduro travelled last April
to China to renegotiate its existing debt by
adding a US$ 5 billion loan to save its eco-
nomy (Ellsworth 2015).
The Case of Ecuador: from the Neoliberal
Financial Crisis to Revolution of Correa
Sobered by the debt crisis from the 80s,
Ecuador started a series of restructuring pro-
grams during the 90s, in accordance with
international nancial institutions to imple-
ment the neoliberal guidelines of the Was-
hington Consensus. Nazmi (2001:727) has
claimed that the reckless implementation of
such reforms caused dangerous macroecono-
mic imbalances to the Ecuadorian economy,
leading to a profound crisis which resulted
in the loss of its national currency.
There are 3 fundamental policies which led
the Ecuadorian state to its economic collap-
se. First, a reckless scheme of privatization
that did not match the national reality of the
state. Second, the articial imposition of a
pegged exchange rate that produced a lack
of liquidity and speculation resulting from
dangerous liberal prescriptions. And third,
the lack of autonomy of the state administra-
tion to produce regulatory policies to prohi-
bit irresponsible practices from a weakened
and corrupt private banking sector.
In 1992 the American-born Sixto Duran
Ballen was elected as the 37th president of
Ecuador. Duran Ballen, who was conside-
red a pro-neoliberal republican, implemen-
ted an innovation model in Ecuador. Such
a model included provisions to reduce the
Ecuadorian public decit through austerity
measures and a privatization scheme of the
national companies. In 1993, the Ecuadorian
congress approved the plan through two le-
gislations. First, the Budgetary Law of the
Public Sector, and second, the ‘Privatization
and Modernization Law’.
Both regulations were aimed to downsize
the government spending, privatize public
companies and enhance international com-
petition. The rst regulation delivered rapid
results. The state reduced its public-sector
expenditure from 31.4% of total GDP in
1987 to 24% in 1994, producing a surplus
of 0.6% of the GDP in the Ecuadorian balan-
ce of payments at the end of that year. Such
31
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
an outstanding short-term result generated a
compensation coming from the IMF, which
reduced the interest rates for the Ecuadorean
loans by up to 5% (Nazmi 2001:728-729).
In 1995, because of the budget cuts that cau-
sed a reduction of labour places in the pu-
blic sector, the unemployment rates started
to increase rapidly. Furthermore, the privati-
zation scheme was still lacking results. The
Ecuadorian state had achieved privatization
of only 11 enterprises while Argentina and
Bolivia, which were following the same po-
licy guidelines, had accomplished privatisa-
tion of 131 and 57 companies respectively
(Nazmi 2001:730). The Ecuadorian eco-
nomy, therefore, was not able to expand as
was expected. Furthermore, the private sec-
tor lacked the eciency to produce enough
employment to compensate for jobs lost in
the public sector during the adjustment pe-
riod.
To attract foreign investment, the Ecuado-
rian government followed neoliberal pres-
criptions that were applied by the rest of the
administrations in the region which dictated
the liberalization of capital movements to
provide further nancial security to foreign
investors. Owing to this, the Ecuadorian ad-
ministration decided to reform its nancial
legislation. The reforms included the possi-
bility of the creation of US$ Dollar accounts
in local banks, the establishment of oshore
accounts, and a pegged exchange rate for the
national currency.
For several scholars including Nazmi (2001),
this was the beginning of what would beco-
me the nancial crisis of 1999. After a while,
the results delivered by the new legislation
diverged from what the government was ex-
pecting. In the rst place the freedom of ca-
pital movements along with the constitutio-
nal reforms repealing the state ownership of
strategic resources as oil and energy, instead
of bringing real and long-term investors, at-
tracted short-term capital investments, better
known as swallow capitals.
The major part of the oil revenues was trans-
ferred outside of the state, due the absence of
capital movement regulations (Berriosa Ma-
rakb & Morgensternc 2011:675-681). The
neoliberal guidelines were clearly providing
a list of benets to the private entities, whi-
le the rates of poverty and unemployment
were critical in the state, demonstrating that
the foreign investment prescriptions mean
neither economic growth nor social develo-
pment.
The collateral eects of the new nancial le-
gislation were inevitable. Since it permitted
the banking sector to generate oshore and
US$ Dollar accounts, the Ecuadorian nan-
cial institutions of that time restructured their
balance sheets to reposition their portfolios
away from Sucres and into US$ Dollars. In
this process, the banks, which were poor-
ly regulated, expanded their balance sheets
recklessly. Imprudent practices included a
relaxed credit risk analysis and resulted in
a credit rise of 48% per year during 1994 to
1996.
Such unhedged exposure to dollar liabili-
ties conditioned the Ecuadorian monetary
policy, which prevented the Central Bank
from devaluating its currency. Such a situa-
tion not only undermined the Ecuadorian
exporting sectors, but also created a moral
hazard for the banks, which continued with
their careless operations, which triggered a
rapid expansion in the Ecuadorian internal
debt gures, as well as a massive increase
in its percentage of debt in foreign curren-
cies which by 1998 were about US$ 987.03
million, from which 91% was in foreign cu-
rrencies (Banco Central del Ecuador 2003).
Nazmi (2001:733-734) argued that such ar-
ticially pegged exchange rate turned all the
previous economic diculties into a full-e-
dged nancial crisis which was made worse
by external factors such as a belic conict
with Peru as well as a series of governamen-
tal corruption scandals. These caused the fai-
lure of the programs that aimed to stabilize
the Sucre exchange rate.
As a consequence, the Central Bank was for-
ced to increase the real interest rates from
1.9% in 1992 to 36.2% in 1999 to encourage
investors to keep their holdings in Sucres.
Because of such desperate policies in con-
junction with public speculation, investors
started to send their money overseas causing
32
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
a lack of liquidity in the nancial sector and
resulting in the insolvency of seven banks
including Filanbanco.
The government monetized their bank losses
causing the collapse of the exchange rate an-
chor. In 1999, the Sucre depreciated around
200% and ination was about 90%. Facing
social disintegration and economic catas-
trophe, the government took the decision to
freeze all bank accounts for one year and in
2000 announced the intention to dollarize
the economy (Nazmi 2001:733-734).
During a ten-year period (1996-2006), Ecua-
dorians observed seven dierent leaders oc-
cupying the position of president. However,
none of the leaders can provide any type of
improvement to the Ecuadorian economy or
to the standards of living of their citizens.
Nonetheless, in 2007, Ecuadorians elected
Rafael Correa as their head of state. Correa
was a populist university lecturer, with an
academic background in economics who
did not have links to the traditional politi-
cal parties. This fact caused his popularity to
spread rapidly among the electorate, which
was tired of the traditional representatives
(Jaramillo-Jassir 2012:151-152). In 2007,
once elected, the new administration started
its revolutionary process which substituted
the neoliberal regime policies established
in Ecuador since the 80s with policies fo-
llowing a model of endogenous growth pri-
marily favouring the working class.
To legitimate their actions in the political
and in the legal eld, a referendum, mainly
intended to produce a new constitution that
included all these reforms, was proposed.
The result was approved by an overwhel-
ming majority of 80% of the electorate.
Furthermore, the new constitution project
which proposed a more egalitarian system,
was accepted the following year by 65% of
the electorate (Becker 2011:49-51).
Following the constitutional prescriptions
based on the Sumac Kawsay, an ancient
indigenous belief that proposes an austere,
socialist and ‘good’ way of living, the Ecua-
dorian administration repatriated and mo-
bilized the international monetary reserves
which were previously deposited in foreign
banks, towards public nancial entities and
national banks. The use of national savings
has been condemned as scally irresponsi-
ble, but the new constitution established that
scal policy cannot be divergent from gene-
rating incentives for productive investment.
Between 2007 and 2011, public investment
as a percentage of GDP grew at an average
rate of 11.7%. Correspondingly, social in-
vestment reached 26% of public spending in
2011 (Banco Central del Ecuador 2014). It
has, therefore, been possible for the admi-
nistration to provide absolute coverage for
enrolment in primary, middle schools and
high schools and to eliminate costs for medi-
cal consultation. In addition, the left-winged
agenda proposed a network of social inclu-
sion, the continuation of subsidies in basic
services, and as well a series of programs to
enhance the reduction of poverty and wage
inequality (Ramírez Gallegos 2011:11-12).
Ecuador was not receiving the maximum
utility from such industry; a situation attri-
butable to the fact that 53.7% of oil produc-
tion of that time belonged to private compa-
nies. Furthermore, as was mentioned before,
the type of contract that the state maintained
with the corporations was not protable at
all due to the major income was coming
from renting the land rather than from pro-
duction. This is the reason why, in 2010, the
project of nationalization and renegotiation
of contracts started, following the constitu-
tional guidelines which dictate that strategic
resources belong to Ecuadorians.
By 2012, the private production of oil was
reduced to 25.6%., the activities of compa-
nies like Texaco-Chevron and OXY were
passed to the national oil company of Ecua-
dor, Petro Ecuador. This re-nationalization
of strategic resources allowed the Ecua-
dorian state to maximize benets from the
commodity boom of the last decade (Berrio-
sa Marakb & Morgensternc 2011:675-681).
These series of reforms and the repossession
of strategic resources has provided Correa’s
administration with a considerable increase
in public revenues. As a matter of fact, Ecua-
dorian exportation revenue soared from US$
14,556.2 million in 2007 to US$ 26,067.1
33
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
million in 2014 of which the oil revenue
share represents 47% of total exportations
and 66% of the raw materials exportations.
Hence the nationalization scheme has been
a crucial factor for the maintenance of the
social policies that Correa’s administration
has implemented.
On the other hand, the new constitution of
Ecuador prohibited any type of outsourcing
and hourly-paid activities. Forcing priva-
te companies to provide full-time contracts
with fully remunerated salaries as well as
social healthcare and a 15% share of prots
to workers. By 2006, 800,000 workers were
part of outsourcing companies. This repre-
sented 17% of the labour force. Thus, thou-
sands of workers were introduced into the
formal sector, which grew from 38% from
2009 to 45% in 2010 (Banco Central del
Ecuador 2014).
The working class, as was expected, de-
monstrated satisfaction with these measu-
res. However, the private sector experienced
considerable downsizing. It was alleged that
it was unmanageable to maintain the same
number of workers with this new package of
benets. This was reected in the unemplo-
yment gures that grew from 7.9% in 2009
to 9.1% in 2010 (Banco Central del Ecuador
2014), (Uquillas 2007:37). To ght against
the rise of unemployment, the government
generated jobs by creating new state enti-
ties. Since 2007, six national ministries in
addition to a considerable number of regio-
nal secretaries and regulatory entities, were
created.
This generated 110,000 new jobs between
2008 and 2014. Furthermore, in the last se-
ven years, the minimum wage has grown
100%, from US$ 170 in 2007 to US$ 340
in 2014. In the following graphs, it is pos-
sible to notice that not only has the unem-
ployment rate fallen, employment in formal
sectors has grown too. This could show that
more workers are nowadays able to receive
better work conditions, fully-paid salaries
and social benets. However, most employ-
ment generated in Ecuador has been the pro-
duct of the creation of public sector entities.
In 2013, 20.68% of all formal employment
were bureaucrats who do not necessary ge-
nerate revenue for the state. In fact, it repre-
sents an enormous scal cost for the state to
maintain such jobs.
The key role of China on the Ecuadorian
Buen Vivir
The Buen Vivir could be perceived as a so-
cialist model, which pursues to improve the
standards of living of the Ecuadorians by re-
ducing poverty and redistributing the wealth
by creating pro-environmental and sustai-
nable policies (SENPLADES 2009). The
results of the Buen Vivir model, until 2014,
34
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
had been remarkable.
Based on socioeconomic macro indicators,
Ecuador not only expanded its economy by
maintaining a consistent GDP annual grow-
th, which grew from 3.5% to 7.9%, but has
also lifted 10% of its total population from
poverty and, as was mentioned before, redu-
ced its unemployment rates.
Furthermore, the socialist policies have im-
proved the rate of secondary school enrol-
ment up to 87% in 2013 from 46% in 2007
and reduced infant mortality rate. Ecuador
also has seen an expansion of its industrial
sectors and in general terms, living con-
ditions of the Ecuadorians have been im-
proved (Cepal 2015). This brief overview
demonstrates how socialist policies have in-
deed demonstrated real development in the
Ecuadorian state. Nevertheless, the ecacy
of such endogenous plan development, as it
has been described in the Ecuadorian natio-
nal policy plan, has gone along with a series
of exogenous factors, including the general
expansion in the global commodity markets
and alternatives for nancial assistance that
China has provided to the Ecuadorian gover-
nment.
Until 2013, Ecuador had signed 4 agree-
ments with the Chinese government. The
contracts prescribed and anticipated the sale
of a xed number of oil barrels, so that the
Ecuadorian government could receive -
nancial assistance from the China Develop-
ment Bank at oating interest of around 7%.
Consequently, the Ecuadorian foreign debt
rose from US$ 7392 million in 2009 to US$
16913 million in 2014, from which 37.6%
is owed to China, (Banco Central del Ecua-
dor 2014). Furthermore, at the beginning of
2015, the Ecuadorian economy was shrin-
king because of the fall of oil prices. This
situation encouraged Rafael Correa to visit
China to negotiate further lines of credit
with Chinese ocials.
After Correa attended the ministerial mee-
ting of the Forum of China and the Com-
munity of Latin American and Caribbean
States (CELAC), Correa reunited on various
occasions with his counterpart Xi Jinping,
resulting in the signing of a series of con-
tracts which included new lines of Chinese
credits that reached US$ 7500 million, from
which 26.6% has been designated merely to
compensate scal imbalances produced by
the downfall of the oil prices, while the rest
will be used to nance the construction of
what will be the biggest renery in Ecuador.
Villavicencio (2013), who has analysed the
nature of Chinese oil contracts, exposed the
downsides of the Chinese cooperation sche-
me. He demonstrated that although the ori-
ginal aim of the Asian power was to secure
energy supplies to meet burgeoning demand,
nowadays, Chinese companies can freely
trade a signicant amount of Ecuadors cru-
de oil exports. In 2013 only 46.5% of Chine-
se-controlled Ecuadorian oil exports went to
China, with the balance resold to other coun-
tries, primarily the United States.
He concluded in 2013 that Ecuador will be a
victim of a debt trap again compromising the
sovereignty policies of the country. By 2015,
such predictions seemed to have been ma-
king sense. With the continuing decline of
oil prices, Ecuadorian ocials have found
themselves in a tricky position. If they want
to perpetuate the ‘Good Living’ model, they
35
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
have to increase the taxation base, apply
austerity measures or acquire more debt. All
alternatives are expected to generate critical
outcomes.
The rise in taxes and the measures taken du-
ring 2015 have generated a series of protests
and rioting in the main cities of Ecuador.
Such a situation not only has destabilized
the political order, but also slowed produc-
tivity. Furthermore, the low prices of oil,
which translates in a reduction of revenue
for the state, will aect its ability to make
repayment of debts, generating a situation in
which a share of the future loans that Ecua-
dor acquire will have to be used for the re-
payment of interest and scal imbalances, as
has happened in the rst period of 2015.
Hence the contraction of the prices of com-
modities in the global markets has expo-
sed the pitfalls of socialist models in Latin
America, which have evidently demonstra-
ted to be maintainable only due to a market
boom, rather than to real expansion within
the productivity sectors. Furthermore, rec-
kless social expenditure has been upheld by
carelessly expanding foreign debt and com-
promising the allocation of strategic resour-
ces for various years, currently around 80%
of Ecuadors exported oil is handled by Chi-
nese rms, limiting the state ability to secure
the best market price for its crude (Villavi-
cencio 2013 ).
The Yasuni case is a clear demonstration of
Chinese power. It demonstrates that they
have great inuence on Ecuadorian poli-
cy-making, especially in energy and com-
mercial matters. China has leveraged its in-
uential power not only by generating large
sums of debt, but also by controlling the fu-
ture oil production of Ecuador. Chinese oil
companies have displaced Western compa-
nies from Ecuadorian territory and have gai-
ned enough resources to inuence govern-
mental decisions in favour of their interests.
On the other hand, Ecuadorian ocials have
entered a situation of dependency in which
the sovereignty of its policies is reliant upon
ensuring the interests of a hegemonic power
are fullled.
The Ecuadorian constitution prohibits any
type of extraction of natural resources in
protected areas. However, from 2016 over
846 million barrels of oil will be drilled
from the ITT block (Ishpingo, Tambococha
and Tiputini), located in the Yasuní National
Park. The Yasuni, which is in the Ecuado-
rian Amazon region, was designated by the
UNESCO as biosphere reserve in 1989 and
is claimed to hold more than 100 000 of di-
erent species of ora and fauna, besides
being the home of two uncontacted indige-
nous tribes.
The Yasuni contains around 20% of Ecua-
dors fossil fuel reserves, which is the rea-
son why many energy companies have been
operating in the peripheral areas of the natio-
nal park since the 1970s. However, the core
areas, including the ITT blocks, have never
been touched. Nonetheless, due to external
pressures and scal decits, this situation
has changed. In 2014, the Ecuadorian Natio-
nal Assembly, declared the area as a “natio-
nal interest”, taking away its condition as a
protected area and therefore allowing extrac-
tion of natural resources in such areas.
On February of 2015, it was revealed that the
Ecuadorian government had for some years
been negotiating a further 1-billion-dollar
loan with China, giving Chinese oil compa-
nies the right to explore and exploit the Ya-
suni-ITT oil reserves. Nowadays, Block 14,
part of the ITT, is operated by Petro Oriental,
which is owned by the China National Petro-
leum Corporation (CNPC) and which owns
55%, and Sinopec, which owns the other
45% (Ortiz 2015).
CONCLUSIONS
This paper has outlined the way in which
China has established a demarcated global
scheme of cooperation that has proven to
be attractive to many non-western states.
During the last decades, the development of
China has been remarkable and its inuen-
ce over developing regions has shown that
it is not merely a commercial and economic
power. The massive accumulation of foreign
exchange reserves, the vast quantity of nan-
36
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
cial assistance provided, the increasing share
of participation in natural resource markets
as well as an extensive agenda of bilateral
cooperation are factors that demonstrate the
capabilities of China’s vast global inuence.
The Chinese economic expansion has brou-
ght to developing economies a series of
opportunities and pitfalls. China’s appetite
for commodities has opened a great door for
commercial sectors of the developing eco-
nomies around the globe. Furthermore, the
lending programs of the Chinese Develop-
ment Bank have demonstrated to be a remar-
kable alternative for the IMF or the World
Bank, without regarding the political model
or the ideological line of thought, China has
become since 2001, a sine qua non-for the
contemporary construction of commercial
and foreign policies of the developing and
developed states around the globe.
For Latin American states, which have not
been capable to accomplishing a real deve-
lopment under the regulations of a Western
economic agenda for 30 years, the Chinese
cooperation scheme, which includes nan-
cial assistance and commercialization of
strategic resources has provided them with
the opportunity to generate more autono-
mous and socialist policies, which have de-
monstrated better outcomes than under the
neoliberal guidelines. However, as was de-
monstrated in Chapters 2 and 3, the sustaina-
bility and success of these models are clearly
reliant on Chinese loans and high prices in
commodity markets.
By 2015, the pitfalls of the Chinese coope-
ration system and problems with the Latin
American socialist models have become evi-
dent. The expansion of the economy in Latin
American states has been a direct result of
a boom in the commodity market. Such ex-
traordinary incomes have allowed the states
to recklessly expand their scal expenditure
and to articially develop their economies
and generate several social policies that have
produced political stability. However, since
2014, the global price of commodities has
fallen causing profound decits in the balan-
ce of payments of the states which maintain
such socialist models. Therefore, they have
acquired large sums of debt, especially with
China, to compensate such imbalances. This
situation has demonstrated the unsustainabi-
lity of such models and the large dependency
that they had on endogenous factors.
37
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
BIBLIOGRAPHIC REFERENCES
Banco Central del Ecuador. (2003). Informa-
ción Económica. Quito: Banco Central del
Ecuador. Retrieved from http://www.bce.n.
ec/index.php/informacion-estadistica-1
Banco Central del Ecuador. (2014). Estadís-
ticas Macroeconómicas. Quito: Banco Cen-
tral del Ecuador.
Becker, M. (2011). Correa, Indigenous Mo-
vements, and the Writing of a New Consti-
tution in Ecuador. Latin American Perspec-
tives, 2 (1) 47-62.
Berriosa, R., Marakb, A., & Morgensternc,
S. (2011). Explaining hydrocarbon nationa-
lization in Latin America: Economics and
political ideology. Review of International
Political Economy, 18 (5), 673-697.
Cavallo, Domingo. (2004). Argentina and
the IMF During the Two Bush Administra-
tions. International Finance, 7(1), 137-150.
Cepal. (2015). Cepal Stats. Retrieved from
http://interwp.cepal.org/cepalstat/WEB_ce-
palstat/Portada.asp?idioma=e
Correa, R. (October 13, 2014). Rafael Co-
rrea: el socialismo del siglo xxi, son prin-
cipios no modelos. Reto Perú. (J. Lanata,
Entrevistador). Retrieved from https://www.
youtube.com/watch?v=hYHV6eagENk
Dieterich, H. (2003). Three Criteria in the
Denition of a Socialist Economy. Revista
Internacional de Filosofía Iberoamericana y
Teoría Social, 8 (20), 117-132.
Do Alto, H. (2008). La revolución de Evo
Morales o los caminos sinuosos de la refun-
dación de Boliva. En F. Gaudichaud (Ed.),
El volcán Latinoamericano Izquierdas, mo-
vimientos sociales y neoliberalismo (pp.
164-183). Paris: Textuel.
Ellsworth, B. 2. (20 de abril de 2015). Vene-
zuela recibe 5.000 Millones por nuevo prés-
tamo de China. Reuters.
Francoise, L. (2013). From foreign trade to
international investment: a new step in Chi-
na’s integration with the world economy.
Springer Econ Change Restruct, 46 (1), 25-
43.
Hurrell, A. (2006). Hegemony, liberalism
and global order: what space for would-be
great powers? International Aairs, 82 (1),
1-19.
INE (2007). Instituto Nacional de Estadisti-
ca, Bolivia. Retrieved from http://www.ine.
gob.bo/
Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Censo.
(2014). Indicadores laborales. Quito: INEC.
Jaramillo-Jassir, M. (2012). Populism and
democratic consolidation during Rafael Co-
rrea’s administration. Is it possible to ensure
democracy through populism? Reexión Po-
lítica, 142-153.
León-Manriquez, J., & Hearn, A. (2011).
China Engages Latin America: Tracing the
Trajectory. (1 ed.). London: Lynne Rienner
Publishers.
Manriquez, J., & Álvarez, L. (2014). ‘Mao’s
steps in Monroe’s backyard: towards a Uni-
ted States-China hegemonic struggle in La-
tin America? Revista Brasileira de Política
Internacional, 9 (27), 9-27.
Navarro, R. (2015). La exitosa política eco-
nómica de Kirchner. El Chileno.
Nazmi, N. (2001). Failed Reforms and Eco-
nomic Collapse in Ecuador. The Quartery
Review of Economic and Finnance, 41 (1)
727-735.
Oliva, C. (2010). Argentina’s Relations with
China Opportunities and Challenges. En
A. H. Fernández (Ed.), Latin America Fa-
38
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
cing China South-South Relations beyond
the Washington Consensus (113-129). Ney
York: Berghahn Books.
Opec. (2015). OPEC, Venezuela. Retrieved
from http://www.opec.org/opec_web/en/
about_us/171.htm
Ortiz, F. (January 2015). China, Latin Ame-
rica and the environment. Retrieved from
http://dialogochino.net/yasuni-silent-invest-
ment/
Oxford Analytica. (2014). ECUADOR: Ya-
suní deal shows oil under china’s control.
Oxford: Oxford Analytica Ltd.
Panizza, F. (2009). Contemporary Latin
America Development and Democracy be-
yond the Washington Consensus. New York:
Zed Books.
Philips, N. (2011). Re-ordering the Region?
China, Latin America and the Western He-
misphere (Review). European Review of La-
tin American Studies, 90 (1), 89-99.
Poveda, P. (2010) Latin America Facing
China South-South Relations beyond the
Washington Consensus. Ney York: Ber-
ghahn Books.
Quincy, S. (2011). If Not Now, When? Re-
ections on Socialism in the 21st Century.
Capitalism Nature Socialism, 22 (3), 57-72.
Ramirez Gallegos, F. (2011). Political Chan-
ge, State Autonomy, and Post-Neoliberalism
in Ecuador. Latin American Perspectives, 20
(1), 1-15.
Rangel, R. & Soto Reyes, E. (2012). El Con-
senso de Washington: la instauración de las
políticas neoliberales. América Latina. Polí-
tica y Cultura, 37 (1), 35-64.
Rhys, J. (2010). China’s Global Expansion
and Latin America. Latin American Studies,
Cambridge University Press, 42 (1), 809–
837.
Richard, F. (1990). What Washington means
by policy reforms (comment). In J. William-
son (Ed.), Latin American Adjustment How
much has happened? (21-24). Washington:
Institute for International Economics.
Rowan, M. (2003). Bolivia y el “Consenso
de Washington” se desentienden. Economía
Hemeroteca, 8 (20).
Rudd, K. (2015). Are China and the US doo-
med to conict? Colorado: TED talks.
SENPLADES. (2009). Plan Nacional para
el Buen Vivir 2009-2013. Quito: SENPLA-
DES.
Silva, S. (2015). The boom and crisis of the
Convertibility Plan in Argentina. Brazilian
Journal of Political Economy, 3 (35), 325-
342.
Svampa, M. (2008). Argentina, del que se
vayan todos a la exacerbación de lo nacio-
nal-popular. En F. Gaudichaud (Ed.), El vol-
cán Latinoamericano Izquierdas, movimien-
tos sociales y neoliberalismo (231-250).
Paris: Textuel.
Torres, D. (2015). Venezuela tiene el doble
de ministerios que otros países. El Universal.
Toussaint, E. (2003). La crisis de la deuda
en América Latina en los siglos XIX y XX.
Seminario Internacional “América Latina y
el Caribe: salir del impase de la deuda y del
ajuste”. Brusels.
Uquillas, C. (2007). El outsourcing en el
Ecuador. Observatorio de la Economía La-
tinoamericana.
Urdinez, F. (2014). The Political Economy
of the Chinese Market Economy Status gi-
ven by Argentina and Brazil. Ciencias So-
ciais-Universidade de São Paulo.
39
REVISTA CHAKIÑAN, 2018, Nº.5, AGOSTO, (18-39)
ISSN 2550-6722
Villavicencio, F. (2013). Ecuador Made in
China (1st ed.). Quito: American Institute
for democracy.
Williamson, J. (1990). Latin American Ad-
justment. Washington: Institute for Interna-
tional Economics.
World Bank. (2014). Global Economic Mo-
nitor (GEM) Commodities. Retrieved from
http://databank.worldbank.org/data/re-
ports.aspx?source=global-economic-moni-
tor-(gem)-commodities#
Wu, F. & De Wei, K. (2014). From Finan-
cial Assets to Financial Statecraft: the case
of China and emerging economies of Africa
and Latin America. Journal of Contempo-
rary China, 89 (23), 781-803.